There was a time that fishing was fun and about “washing the
soul” (Hoover 1963). Serious anglers
were also serious conservationist and devoted to cleaning up and eliminating
pollution from our waters. Can you think
of cost of services that have not increased in past ten years? No? Me
neither. Why is it that fishing licenses
do not increase with cost of living? Why
is it that some state legislators are so reluctant to raise the price of a
fishing license? Most states face a
pressing dilemma on how to continue to fund the mission of the state fish and
wildlife agency.
In 2018, legislators in Louisiana and Pennsylvania rejected
calls for license fee increases (basic fishing license would increase from$9.50 to $13.50 for 709,000 licensed fishermen in Louisiana). The Pennsylvania proposal would have raised
the license fee $6.50 after 12 years at $21 (2.6%/year). Meanwhile,
Colorado’s Senate approved an increase in fishing license prices that have not
increased since 2005 (2.46% per year) and forwarded legislation to the House.
Photo by Tyler Willmon. Creative Commons Source. |
If you fish, you should be aware of these four facts from
(AFWA 2018):
- Most state fish and wildlife agencies receive only modest or no appropriations from the state treasury and must seek legislative approval for increasing license prices. (Schaeffer et al. 2018).
- Number of sport anglers increased only 8% between 2011 and 2016. This rate of increase is not enough to keep up with rising costs of fish conservation.
- Almost 83% of current adult participants were introduced to the sport of fishing during childhood. After the age of 12, it is much less likely for a person to try fishing.
- More than 45% of angling participants are approaching 50 years of age. During the next 25 years, these anglers will begin to age out of the sport.
One response to
shrinking revenues is to Recruit, Retain, and Reactivate license buying anglers,
or R3 for short. Organizations, such as the Recreational Boating and Fishing
Foundation, the American Sportfishing Association, the sportfishing industry,
and fishing equipment manufacturers are partnering with federal agencies and
the Association of Fish and Wildlife Agencies to achieve the ambitious national
goal of 60 million anglers in 60 months. In 2016 there were 35.75 million
anglers so the goal represents a 4.85% increase in anglers (USDOI 2016).
The typical US
citizen does not fish and that may be due to access, awareness, skills, or motivation. Globally, participation in recreational
fishing is ~10.5% of the populace and diminishing interest is expected without
marketing and dedicated management after industrialization (Arlinghaus et al.
2015). In Ontario, participation rates
decrease in dense urban centers and increase in areas with higher fish
densities but there are other influences on participation (Hunt et al. 2005).
Participation in recreational fishing related to population density and fish density in Ontario (Hunt et al. 2017).
|
Is Angler R3 the answer? Can you make me have fun? Some agencies
have begun to implement the Angler R3 tools but it’s too early to tell if R3 will be sufficient. Others have been slow to begin because the
average cost for already strapped agency may be about ~$250,000 in typical
state agencies. But without aggressive
management intervention, the participation rates will stagnate or continue to
decline. And every time a license rate
is increased dramatically after years of being fixed, angling participation
declines more. Getting more kids to fish before age 12 will prove to be a
daunting challenge over the next 2 decades as current anglers over 50 years of
age begin to leave the sport. Children
are less connected to nature in our modern society. Richard Louv (2008) coined the term “nature deficit
disorder” to explain that a child separated from nature is a child deprived of
health and happiness. Children in our modern society increasingly suffer from a
variety of syndromes, such as asthma, dyslexia, attention deficit disorder, and
obesity. These and other threats to our children' well-being may interfere with their fishing.
What is the right approach to raising revenues for fish
conservation and management? Will it
be more anglers paying the same or more
citizens paying less? In my opinion fishing
should be fun, not complicated and not part of non-stop marketing. Years of stagnated budgets concern directors
of fish and wildlife agencies. Fish and
wildlife are public trust resources and the states are trustees. Even though the entire public benefits from
the work of fish and wildlife conservation, the “pay to play” model has
dominated the US approach to conservation funding. But the world is changing and our fish and
wildlife agencies need to adapt.
Public trust thinking is about making certain that benefits
provided by ecosystems are available to everyone, including future generations
to explore their interests. The public trust doctrine is based on English
common law. In numerous challenges, the public trust doctrine has been firmly
established in the US and establishes the responsibility of government, both
state and federal, to conserve and manage fish and wildlife for public benefit (Sax
1970; Batcheller et al. 2018). The state agency is the trust manager, applying collective
technical expertise to inform and implement policy. States are to manage the fish and wildlife
so that the populations are sustained for the current and future citizens, who
are beneficiaries of the trust (Schaeffer et al. 2018). State fish and wildlife agencies are “front
lines of conservation” and control both the technical expertise and capital
resources to manage fish for public trust purposes (Trushenski et al. 2018). As such they manage fish, wildlife, and
habitats in the public trust and use fiscal resources provided for law
enforcement, research, monitoring, hatcheries, and other management programs. But
agency effectiveness has been constrained by reliance on the “pay to play”
funding model.
Public trust thinking is based on four principles (Hare and
Bossey 2014):
- Human well-being is dependent on the benefits provided by ecosystems.
- Certain resources are not suitable for exclusive private ownership
- All beneficiaries are equal.
- Trustees are bound by fiduciary obligations and are publicly accountable
The vision of the modern fish and wildlife agencies embrace
public trust thinking. For example, the
vision of Virginia Department of Game and Inland Fisheries (VDGIF) is “Leading
wildlife conservation and inspiring people to value the outdoors and their role
in nature.” The Florida Fish and
Wildlife Conservation Commission is “managing fish and wildlife resources for
their long-term wellbeing and the benefit of people.” The mission of the VDGIF reflects
public trust thinking {even if the name “Game and Inland Fisheries” does not.} The mission of VDGIF is to:
•
Conserve and manage wildlife populations
and habitat for the benefit of present and future generations.
•
Connect people to Virginia’s outdoors
through boating, education, fishing, hunting, trapping, wildlife viewing, and
other wildlife-related activities.
•
Protect people and property by promoting
safe outdoor experiences and managing human-wildlife conflicts.
The FY Budget for VDGIF is $62,833,365 and most is allocated
to wildlife and freshwater fisheries management ($45,686,094) while the
remainder supports administration and support ($9,051,353) and boating safety
and regulation ($8,095,918). These funds
come from license revenues ($46,431,590) and federal trust ($16,278,143) and
support 496 positions. Expansion of the agency programs is dependent on growth
in participation. Expanded funding is
needed to deal with permitting energy development, law enforcement of motorboat
and ATVs’, watershed restoration, endangered species consultation and
litigation, and capital improvements.
Federal aid is derived from the sale of fishing, hunting,
and trapping licenses, along with federal funding via the Sport Fish
Restoration and Pittman–Robertson Wildlife Restoration programs, derived from
the sale of firearms and ammunition and fishing equipment and boat motor fuels.
These federal user-pay programs began
with Pittman Robertson in 1937 and Dingell Johnson Act in 1950. The user pay/user benefit model relies on a
narrow perception of the beneficiaries of the public trust. Consequently, it is natural that the trustees
align themselves closely to those paying the bills. Here is where the
implementation may run counter to the principles of public trust thinking. These
long-standing practices and programs privilege consumptive uses over
nonconsumptive uses of fish and wildlife (Feldpausch-Parker et al. 2017).
The old model appears inadequate and will not provide the
needs for fish and wildlife conservation in the 21st century. Jacobson
et al. (2010) and others maintain that this is fundamentally flawed and does
not provide broad-based funding and benefits to all citizens. For example, the Dingell-Johnson funds are
only eligible for use on sport fish species that have value for sport or
recreation (Schaeffer et al 2018). With
the rise of alternative types of fishing for ‘rough’ fish, small and diverse
fish (microfishing), bowfishing, fish watching, and native fish aquarium hobbyists, the need for
technical support for management is expanding.
These new aquatic sports are slow to develop when traditional sport
fishing dominates the agenda. Only a few
state agencies have secured a dedicated share of state sales tax to address
these broader conservation needs. The
search for new revenues and broader support for fish conservation will
continue.
Photo by Tommy Lyngmo. Creative Commons Source. |
The State Wildlife Grants program (Wildlife Conservation and
Restoration) directs funds for species of greatest conservation needs and
develop wildlife diversity programs. The
original state wildlife action plans identified 12,800 species of greatest
conservation need, and admittedly many states had inadequate coverage of
groups, such as dragonflies and damselflies (Mawdsley et al. 2017). Conserving and managing these poorly studied
and threatened species adds tremendous challenges to agencies, without proving
sufficient revenues.
What can be done now?
First, take kids fishing early and often. Second, buy your fishing license! Finally, the proposed Recovering America's Wildlife
Act has the potential to influence funding for future conservation. Ask your U.S. congressional representative to
support this effort. Information on the bill can be found here.
References
Arlinghaus, R., R.
Tillner, R., and M. Bork. 2015. Explaining participation rates in recreational
fishing across industrialised countries. Fisheries
Management and Ecology 22:45–55.
Association of
Fish and Wildlife Agencies. 2018. Recommendations from the president’s task
force on angler recruitment, retention, and reactivation. 22 pp.
Available from https://www.fishwildlife.org/application/files/2515/2349/7242/AFWA_R3_Taskforce_Report_Final_4.pdf
Batcheller, G.R.,
T.A. Decker, and R.P. Lanka. 2018.
Public trust doctrine and the legal basis for state wildlife
management. Pages 24-38 in T.J. Ryder,
editor. State Wildlife Management and
Conservation, Johns Hopkins University Press.
Feldpausch-Parker,
A.M., I.D. Parker, and E.S. Vidon. 2017.
Privileging consumptive use: A critique of ideology, power, and
discourse in the North American model of wildlife conservation. Conservation
and Society 15:33-40.
Hare, D., and B.
Bossey. 2014. Principles of public trust thinking. Human
Dimensions of Wildlife 19:397-406.
Hoover, H. 1963.
Fishing for fun – and to wash your soul.
Random House. 86 pp.
Hunt, L.M., WA.
E. Bannister, D.A. Drake, S.A. Fera, and T.B. Johnson. 2017. Do fish drive
recreational fishing license sales? North American Journal of Fisheries
Management 37:122-132.
Jacobson, C. A.,
J. F. Organ, D. J. Decker, G. R. Batcheller, and L. Carpenter. 2010. A
conservation institution for the 21st century: Implications for state wildlife
agencies. Journal of Wildlife Management
74:203–209.
Louv, R.
2008. Last child in the woods: Saving
our children from nature-deficit disorder. Algonquin Books, Chapel Hill, North
Carolina, USA.
Mawdsley, J., D.
Palmeri, and M. Humpert. 2017. Aquatic biodiversity in the U.S. state wildlife
action plans. Fisheries 42(6):332-334.
Sax, J. L. 1970.
The public trust doctrine in natural resource law: Effective judicial
intervention. Michigan Law Review
68:471–566.
Schaeffer, J.M.,
M.C. Bambery, P. Gilbert, and G.J. Taylor. 2018. State Fish and Wildlife Agencies and
Conservation: A Special Relationship.
Pages 39- in T.J. Ryder, editor. State Wildlife Management and Conservation,
Johns Hopkins University Press.
Trushenski, J.T.,
G.E. Whelan, and J.D. Bowker. 2018. Why
keep hatcheries? Weighing the economic cost and value of fish production for
public use and public trust purposes. Fisheries 42 https://doi.org/10.1002/fsh.10084
U.S. Department of the Interior, U.S. Fish
and Wildlife Service, and U.S. Department of Commerce, U.S. Census Bureau. 2016
National Survey of Fishing, Hunting, and Wildlife-Associated Recreation. https://wsfrprograms.fws.gov/Subpages/NationalSurvey/nat_survey2016.pdf
Great piece...thanks Dr. Orth!
ReplyDeleteBrian Clark, VT FiW Class of '92